logo

Corruption, optimal, taxation and growth

How does the presence of corruption affect the optimal mix between consumption and income taxation?
PUBLIC Barreto, 10.1177/1091142103251589 FINANCE ARTICLE Alm REVIEW / CORRUPTION CORRUPTION, OPTIMAL TAXATION, AND GROWTH RAUL A. BARRETO University of Adelaide JAMES ALM Georgia State University How does the presence of corruption affect the optimal mix between consumption and in- come taxation? In this article, the authors examine this issue using a simple neoclassical growth model, with a self-seeking and corrupt public sector. They find that the optimal tax mix in a corrupt economy is one that relies more heavily on consumption taxes than on income taxes, relative to an economy without corruption. Their model also allows them to investigate the effect of corruption on the optimal (or welfare-maximizing) size of government, and their results indicate that the optimal size of government balances the wishes of the corrupt public sector for a larger government, and so greater opportunities for corruption, with those in the private sector who prefer a smaller government. Not sur- prisingly, the optimal size of government is smaller in an economy with corruption than in one without corruption. Keywords: endogenous growth; corruption; taxation 1. INTRODUCTION Governments have a natural monopoly over the provision of many publicly provided goods and services, such as property rights, law and order, and contract enforcement, and a selfless and impartial govern- ment official would provide these services efficiently, at their mar- ginal cost. However, it has long been recognized that public officials are often self-seeking, and such officials may abuse their public posi- tion for personal gain. These actions include such behavior as de- manding bribes to issue a license, awarding contracts in exchange for money, extending subsidies to industrialists who make contributions, PUBLIC FINANCE REVIEW, Vol. 31 No. X, Month 2003 1- DOI: 10.1177/1091142103251589 © 2003 Sage Publications 1 2 PUBLIC FINANCE REVIEW stealing from the public treasury, and selling government-owned com- modities at black-market prices. In their entirety, these actions can be characterized as abusing public office for private gain, or “corruption” (Shleifer and Vishny 1993). The idea of self-seeking government agents, particularly those who provide public services through public bureaus, is hardly new.1 The typical bureaucrat is assumed to face a set of possible actions, to have personal preferences among the outcomes of the possible actions, and to choose the action within the possible set that he or she most prefers. Corruption can often result and can become ingrained and systemic in a society’s institutions. However, despite the widespread recognition of corruption, it is only recently that systematic analyses of its causes, effects, and reme- dies have been undertaken.2 For example, there is now evidence that corruption distorts incentives, misallocates resources, lowers invest- ment and economic growth, reduces tax revenues, and redistributes in- come and wealth, among other things.3 The prevention of corruption is a more difficult issue. Suggested remedies include the obvious ones of rewards for honesty and penalties for dishonesty. Increasing the trans- parency in government decision making, improving the accountabil- ity of public officials, and, more generally, reducing the scope of gov- ernment via privatization, deregulation, and other market reforms have been shown to help reduce or minimize corruption (Klitgaard, MacLean-Abaroa, and Parris, 2000). However, despite these many useful insights, the effects of corrup- tion on the tax structure of a country remain largely unexamined. There is a large literature on the tax structure that maximizes social welfare in a static setting (e.g., Diamond and Mirrlees, 1970; Atkinson and Stiglitz, 1976), and there has also been much recent work on the appropriate mix of consumption versus income taxes to generate max- imum growth (e.g., Jones, Manuelli, and Rossi, 1993; Stokey and Rebelo, 1995). However, as recently emphasized by Tanzi and Davoodi (2000), the effects of corruption on the structure of a coun- try’s tax system have not been studied, especially in a dynamic setting in which the effects of the tax mix can be examined. Barreto, Alm / CORRUPTION 3 This is our purpose here: to determine the effects of corruption on the optimal mix between consumption and income taxes, using a sim- ple neoclassical growth model with a self-seeking and corrupt public sector.4 In our model, the government is assumed to provide two kinds of public goods: one that enters the utility function of individuals and one that is used as an input in private production. There are two agents, one public and one private, and each maximizes a utility function that depends on consumption of the public good and also of a private good, where the public good is subject to congestion. The government fi- nances its activities by a consumption tax and an income tax. Impor- tantly, we follow Shleifer and Vishny (1993) by assuming that the public agent has the ability to exploit monopoly rents in the provision of a public good to private industry; that is, there is corruption institu- tionalized within the public sector. The government is assumed to choose its instruments to maximize a social welfare function that is the sum of public and private agent utilities.5 Our results indicate that the presence of corruption significantly al- ters the mix of consumption and income taxes. Compared to an econ- omy without corruption, the socially optimal tax structure with a cor- rupt government involves a greater reliance on consumption taxes and a smaller use of income taxes. However, this mix depends on the social welfare weights of the public and private agents: The public agent pre- fers more use of income taxes than consumption taxes because the public agent’s income from corruption cannot be taxed under an in- come tax, whereas the private agent has the opposite preference. In ad- dition, our results are to examine the effect of corruption on the opti- mal (or welfare-maximizing) size of government. Our results show that this optimal government size balances the wishes of the corrupt public sector for a larger government and so greater opportunities for corruption, with the desire of the private sector for a smaller govern- ment. Not surprisingly, the optimal size of government is smaller in an economy with corruption than in one without corruption. The next section presents our model and discusses its solution. Sec- tion 3 examines our results, and our conclusions are in Section 4. An appendix contains a complete description and solution of our analytic model. 4 PUBLIC FINANCE REVIEW 2. A THEORETICAL MODEL OF ENDOGENOUS GROWTH WITH A CORRUPT GOVERNMENT Consider a simple endogenous growth model with a public good sector and two representative agents, one representing the public sec- tor and one for the private sector. The government is assumed to pro- vide a public good for private consumption and one also for private production. In the latter case, the public agent is assumed to have the ability to exploit the potential for monopoly rents in the provision of the public good. The government finances its production with separate taxes on consumption and on income. The public and private agents optimize intertemporally, and the government maximizes social wel- fare, defined as the unweighted sum of individual utilities. Government can be viewed as providing two kinds of public goods. Public goods are nonrival and nonexclusive, and, as such, they can serve two basic and distinct functions. One is to give utility to consum- ers by providing them with certain goods that they value but that are unlikely to be provided in efficient amounts by private markets. The classic example of this type of public good is national defense; other examples include public parks, swimming pools, and similar kinds of public facilities. We denote this type of public good a public consump- tion good, or zt, where the subscript t represents the time period. A second function of public goods is to facilitate private produc- tion. Contract enforcement falls into this category, as does much pub- lic infrastructure like roads and bridges. This type of public good may therefore be thought of as an intermediate good in the production pro- cess. We call this type of public good a public production good, or gt. Production of this good depends on the amount of public capital k1t. The public production good gt is assumed to be an input in the produc- tion of the private output, which is denoted yt. Private production also requires the use of private capital, or k2t. There are two agents. Agent 1 is assumed to be the public agent, and Agent 2 is the private agent. Following Shleifer and Vishny (1993), corruption is introduced by allowing Agent 1 to control the production and distribution of the public production good gt; that is, the public agent is assumed to derive revenue, or corruption income ψt, by the ability to extract monopoly rents from the sale of the public produc- tion good gt to private industry.6 Agent 2 controls production of the pri- Barreto, Alm / CORRUPTION 5 vate good yt, which is produced with private capital k2t and the public production good gt. Capital is completely mobile between the public and private sectors. The two representative agents receive income from separate sources. The private agent has income only from the production of the private good yt. In contrast, the public agent receives all income ψt from the ability to exercise market power over the distribution of the public production good gt to private industry. The intuition follows Shleifer and Vishny (1993) and is straightforward. Private industry re- quires some degree of services, or cooperation, from the public sector to produce anything (e.g., licenses, contract enforcement, public in- frastructure). However, these services are ultimately in the hands of individuals within government, and these officials need not provide their services free of charge. In fact, because private industry really may have no choice but to accept whatever degree of public coopera- tion that is offered at whatever price is asked, a public official may act as a monopolist over the administration of this particular arm of the government. The implication is that the public agent receives the mo- nopoly rent, or corruption income ψt, from the provision of the public production good. Although their income sources differ, the agents are faced with sim- ilar intertemporal utility functions, in which utility depends on con- sumption of the private consumption good cit and the public consump- tion good zt, over an infinite planning horizon, where i denotes Agent 1 or 2. Each agent’s utility function takes the following general form: ∞ ∞ − ρt − ρt 1 Ui = ∫e • u( cit , zt ) • dt = ∫e • • ( cit • ztσ )γ • dt, i = 1, 2, (1) t=0 t=0 γ where ρ is the pure rate of time preference, σ measures the impact of public consumption on the welfare of the individual agent, and γ is re- lated to the intertemporal elasticity of substitution.7 The government derives revenue from an income tax and a con- sumption tax, and we model these taxes using the same approach as Turnovsky (1996). The income of the private agent is taxed at rate. However, because income from corruption is by definition illegal in- come, the income of the public agent is assumed to be untaxed. In con- 6 PUBLIC FINANCE REVIEW trast, consumption expenditures of both agents are taxed at rate τ. To- tal government tax revenue is denoted by χt, where χt = ω • (c1t + c2t) + τ • (yt – ψt). (2) Aggregate public goods χt are subject to congestion, represented as 1 −δ δ χ  zt = χ t •  t  , (3)  yt  where δ is the congestion coefficient and yt is aggregate private output. For the level of public services zt available to the individual to be con- stant over time, it must be the case that χ& t y& = (1 − δ ) • t , (4) χt yt where a dot over a variable denotes a time derivative. By representing public goods in this manner, less-than-perfect degrees of non- excludability and non-rivalness may be considered. Analytically, con- gestion affects the growth rate and therefore the model’s solution through the term for the marginal utility of capital that appears in the Euler equations.8 The public agent maximizes utility, subject to the following con- straints: ψt = (r1t – r2t) • k1t = Pgt • gt – r2t • k1t (5) ψt = c1t • (1 + ω) + s1t (6) gt = ν • k1t (7) kt = k1t + k2t (8) k&t = s1 t + s 2 t − ξ • kt , (9) where yt = total output at Time t gt = public production good at Time t Barreto, Alm / CORRUPTION 7 Pgt = price of the public good at Time t ν = inverse productivity factor = coefficient of “red tape,” 0≤ν≤1 cit = Agent i’s consumption at Time t, i = 1, 2 sit = Agent i’s saving at Time t, i = 1, 2 ψt = corruption at Time t r1t = the marginal product of capital in the public sector at Time t r2t = the after-tax marginal product of capital in the private sector at Time t k1t = capital used in the public sector production function at Time t k2t = capital used in the private sector at Time t ρ = the pure rate of time preference ξ = the economy-wide depreciation rate of capital ω = the consumption tax rate. Equation 5 defines the income of Agent 1, Equation 6 is the public agent’s budget constraint, Equation 7 denotes a linear technology for the public production good, Equation 8 shows the total supply of capi- tal, and Equation 9 is the equation of change for total capital. The pri- vate agent, Agent 2, faces a similar set of constraints: α g  g  yt = k2 t • f  t  = k2 t • A •  t  (10)  k2 t   k2 t  yt = Pgt • gt + r2t • k2t (11) gt = ν • k1t (12) (yt – ψ) • (1 – τ)t = c2t • (1 + ω) + s2t (13) kt = k1t + k2t (14) k&t = s1 t + s 2 t − ξ • kt , (15) where f( ) is the general production function for total output, A and ∀ are coefficients in the production function, and τ is the income tax rate. A bar over a variable signifies that the variable is fixed and given for the agent. Equation 10 specifies the production technology for total output, Equation 11 defines the uses of output, and Equation 13 is the 8 PUBLIC FINANCE REVIEW budget constraint for Agent 2. Other equations are identical to those of Agent 1. The two agents engage in a simple sequential game.9 At any given time, say t = 0, there exists some total supply of capital kt = 0. Agent 1, the public agent, is assumed to go first by choosing the amount of k1t = 0 that is needed to produce the desired amount of the public production good gt = 0. However, Agent 1 is a monopolist in the provision of the public production good to Agent 2 and limits the amount of gt = 0 avail- able to the economy in order to raise its price. The public agent maxi- r mizes utility by choosing k1t = 0 such that Pgt = 1νt , which is endoge- nously determined via a modified golden rule. Corruption income ωt = 0 is paid in final goods. The corrupt agent may devote income toward consumption c1t = 0 or savings s1t = 0, as given in Equation 6, in which Agent 1’s consumption is taxed, but the agent’s income is untaxed. Then, the private agent (Agent 2) maximizes utility, deriving reve- nue from the production of the composite output yt = 0. The private agent accepts as given the monopolistically determined price Pgt = 0 and quantity gt = 0 of the public production good, as set by Agent 1; recall that a bar over a variable means that this variable is fixed and given to the agent. Given this amount of the public production good, Agent 2 devotes all of the remaining capital k2t = 0 to the production of the com- posite output good yt = 0. The allocation of capital between the two sectors is demonstrated in Figure 1. Here, Dki represents the demand for capital in sector i, MRk1 is the corresponding marginal revenue of public sector capital, and ri de- notes the return to capital in sector i. If the public agent behaved com- petitively, capital would be allocated between the sectors so as to equalize the returns to capital in each sector at rpc. However, with mo- nopolistic power, the public agent restricts the allocation of capital to the public sector, thereby generating a monopoly rent of (r1 – r2) k1.10 Recall that Agent 1 goes first by choosing k1t and c1t. More formally, Agent 1 maximizes the present value Hamiltonian, defined as L1 = U1t + πt • [s1t + s2t – ξ • (k1t + k2t)] + µt • [ψt – c1t • (1 + ω) – s1t]. (16) This optimization defines the resulting growth path as Barreto, Alm / CORRUPTION 9 r1 MCk1 r2 r1 rpc rpc r2 Dk2 MRk1 k1 {k1,k2}m {k1,k2}pc k2 k = k1+k2 Figure 1: The Allocation of Capital Between the Public and Private Sectors c&1 t 1 µ& (17) = • t c1 t [ γ • (1 + δ • σ ) − 1] µ t −1  c  = • δ • σ • (1 + ω ) • α 1 t + ν • f ′ − (1 − α ) • (1 − τ )• f − ξ − ρ  [ γ • (1 + δ • σ ) − 1]  k1 t  where the first term in the brackets is the marginal utility of k1t and the second is the marginal product of k1t. The private agent accepts the public agent’s choice of k1t and conse- quently accepts the levels of gt and ψt. Agent 2 then optimizes the pres- ent-value Hamiltonian with respect to c2t and k2t, or L2 = U2t + yt • [s1t + s2t – ξ • (k1t + k2t)] + (18) λt • [(yt – ψt) • (1 – τ) – c2t • (1 + ω) – s2t]. 10 PUBLIC FINANCE REVIEW This optimization defines the growth path as c&2 t 1 ϕ& (19) = • t c2 t [ γ • (1 + δ • σ ) − 1] ϕ t −1  c  = • δ • σ • (1 + α ) • (1 + ω ) • 2 t + f • (1 − α ) • (1 − τ ) − ξ − ρ  [ γ • (1 + δ • σ ) − 1]  k2 t  The balanced growth equilibrium is then defined as c&1 t c&2 t 1 µ& 1 ϕ& = = • t = • t. (20) c1 t c2 t [ γ • (1 + δ • σ ) − 1] µ t [ γ • (1 + δ • σ ) − 1] ϕ t c Notice that each agent’s consumption growth is a function of k 11 tt and c 2t , respectively. k2t Equations 17 and 19 may be solved using the capital accumulation equation to get the following analytic results:11 c1 t y • (1 − τ ) + τ • ψ − ξ • ( k1 t + k2 t ) − k&t = t k1 t (1 + ω ) • k1 t {δ • σ • α • [ yt • (1 − τ ) + τ • ψ − ξ • ( k1 t + k2 t ) − k&t ] • k1−t1 + ν • f ′ − (1 − α ) • (1 − τ ) • f • 2} − (21)  k  δ • σ • (1 − ω ) • (1 − α ) • 1 t + α   k2 t  & −1 c2 t {δ • σ • α • [ yt • (1 − τ ) + τ • ψ − ξ • ( k1t + k2 t ) − kt ] • k1t + ν • f ′ − (1 − α ) • (1 − τ ) • f • 2} = (22) k2 t  k  δ • σ • (1 − ω ) • (1 − α ) + α • 2 t   k1t  The basic solution is illustrated by Figure 2, which depicts a simple Solow-Swan type of growth framework in three dimensions. The model solution determines the relative distribution of public capital k1 versus private capital k2 at any point in time. This solution is repre- sented graphically by two lines in Figure 2. Assuming a capital stock of one, the line s • F • (1 – τ) depicts all possible levels of gross invest- ment as determined by the distribution of public versus private capital; furthermore, because the depreciation rate is equal across sectors, it is represented by a line in {k1, k2} space, where [k1 + k2 = 1]. To illustrate the solution, start from an initial allocation of capital between the sec- tors, given by {k1, k2}0 in Figure 2. As a country that is subject to cor- Barreto, Alm / CORRUPTION 11 Figure 2: Net Investment and the Steady State at k = k1 + k2= 1 ruption moves toward its steady-state equilibrium distribution of capi- tal, or {k1, k2}*, the amount of publicly provided goods increases, implying a lower rate of return on capital, a lower monopoly rent for the public agent, and lower corruption; that is, more public services are provided at lower cost. As a result, the welfare of both agents in- creases at the expense of lower growth. The full model and a discus- sion of its solution are in the appendix. However, the basic solution is characterized by extreme non-linear- ity in the solution for the economy-wide growth rate. Consequently, there exist multiple equilibria for any given choice of k1t and k2t. Fur- thermore, it can be shown that 12 PUBLIC FINANCE REVIEW c$2 t c2 t = ( k1 t , k2 t , α , δ, γ, σ ), (23) k2 t k2 t where a hat “^” denotes an analytic solution and where there is a strict c$ association among these variables such that k 22 tt > 0. Although there likely does exist this same type of association between the analytic so- c$ c$ lutions for k 11 tt and k 22 tt and the model’s coefficients, this association can- c$ c$ not be defined analytically because the analytic solutions to k 11 tt and k 22 tt each contain a k& element, whereas the no-corruption solution to 2 t c$ t k2t does not. Put differently, the multiple equilibria are such that the opti- mal choices of c1 and c2 are related to the analytic results for c$1 t and c$ 2 t by the relation [c$1 t + c$ 2 t = c1t + c2t] at any balanced growth equilibrium k choice of k 12 tt . As a result, numerical solutions are needed to explore the model’s implications for optimal taxation. These simulations are discussed next. 3. SIMULATION RESULTS Some initial insights into the choice of an optimal tax structure can be obtained by observing the effects on welfare of changes in one tax rate, holding the other tax rate constant. Tables 1, 2, and 3 report some of the results of these simulations, and Figures 3, 4, and 5 give a more complete presentation of the welfare effects of different tax mixes. All simulations are done with the following coefficient values: A = 0.1 ν = 1 α = 0.25 ρ = 0.02 γ = 0.11 σ = 0.25 δ = 0.75. Barreto, Alm / CORRUPTION 13 TABLE 1: Steady State at Various Income Tax Rates 1 2 3 4 5 U2 + U1 = 9.337 9.545 9.662 9.689 9.584 U1 = 4.281 4.3313 4.331 4.279 4.151 U2 = 5.056 5.214 5.331 5.411 5.433 k1/k2 = 0.185 0.208 0.226 0.240 0.252 ψ/y = 0.180 0.156 0.131 0.106 0.080 τ= 0.500 0.400 0.300 0.200 0.100 ω= 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 Tax revenue/y = 0.410 0.337 0.261 0.179 0.092 TABLE 2: Steady State: τ = 10% and Various Consumption Tax Rates 1 2 3 4 5 6 U2 + U1 = 9.557 9.575 9.590 9.599 9.5992 9.584 U1 = 4.139 4.147 4.153 4.157 4.1572 4.151 U2 = 5.418 5.428 5.437 5.442 5.4420 5.433 k1/k2 = 0.252 0.252 0.252 0.252 0.252 0.252 ψ/y = 0.080 0.080 0.080 0.080 0.080 0.080 τ= 0.100 0.100 0.100 0.100 0.100 0.100 ω= 0.250 0.200 0.150 0.100 0.050 0.000 Tax revenue/y = 0.203 0.184 0.164 0.142 0.118 0.092 TABLE 3: Steady State: τ = 20% and Various Consumption Tax Rates 1 2 3 4 5 6 U2 + U1 = 9.564 9.592 9.619 9.645 9.669 9.689 U1 = 4.223 4.236 4.247 4.259 4.269 4.279 U2 = 5.341 5.356 5.371 5.386 5.399 5.411 k1/k2 = 0.240 0.240 0.240 0.240 0.240 0.240 ψ/y = 0.106 0.106 0.106 0.106 0.106 0.106 τ= 0.200 0.200 0.200 0.200 0.200 0.200 ω= 0.250 0.200 0.150 0.100 0.050 0.000 Tax revenue/y = 0.272 0.257 0.240 0.221 0.201 0.179 The choice of these specific coefficient values follows Turnovsky (1996). Other values yield similar qualitative results.12 14 PUBLIC FINANCE REVIEW Figure 3: Tax Substitution Effects on Welfare at the Steady State: Public Agent Figure 4: Tax Substitution Effects on Welfare at the Steady State: Private Agent Barreto, Alm / CORRUPTION 15 Figure 5: Tax Substitution Effects on Welfare at the Steady State: Social Welfare In Table 1, income taxes vary from 10% to 50%, whereas consump- tion taxes are set to zero. Note that lower income tax rates generate less corruption (and also greater relative amounts of public capital). How- ever, each agent has a very different preference for income taxes. At a 0% consumption tax rate, the public agent prefers a relatively high in- come tax (about 40%) because Agent 1 does not pay income taxes but nevertheless benefits from the public consumption good provided from tax revenues. In contrast, the private agent prefers a relatively low income tax (about 10%). With a zero consumption tax rate, global welfare is maximized at an income tax rate of more than 20%, a level that can be viewed as balancing the wish of the public agent for a high income tax rate with that of the private agent for a low income tax rate. Tables 2 and 3 present the results of steady states as consumption tax rates vary, with constant 10% and 20% income tax rates, respec- tively. Consumption taxes have significant welfare implications. Un- like with income taxes, each agent’s preferences over consumption taxes are identical; that is, utility for each agent is maximized at the same consumption tax rate. In Table 2, maximum utility occurs at a consumption tax of 5% (with an income tax of 10%) so that at a low in- come tax rate individual and global utilities increase with higher con- 16 PUBLIC FINANCE REVIEW sumption taxes. In contrast, a lower consumption tax of about 10% maximizes utility when the income tax is 0% (Table 3). Because both agents are equally subject to consumption taxes and both agents equally benefit from consumption tax revenue, then both agents ex- hibit the same preferences over consumption taxes.13 The general nature of these results is also depicted in Figures 3, 4, and 5, which demonstrate that agents have very different preferences over the tax mix.14 The public agent generally prefers a mix of a high income tax and a low consumption tax, whereas a private agent has the opposite preference. As demonstrated in Figure 5, the optimum tax mix for society balances these conflicting wishes of the agents. In Tables 1, 2, and 3 (and in Figures 3, 4, and 5), the size of govern- ment varies with the amount of taxes collected. Table 4 and Figure 6 present the results where the relative size of government, defined by χt yt , remains constant but where differing tax mixes are considered at the steady state. As income taxes fall, consumption taxes are increased to compensate for the loss in public revenue. The changing tax mix leads to a decline in relative corruption, which generates in turn a de- crease in the public agent’s utility and an increase in that of the private agent. Conversely, as government relies more heavily on income taxes, the public agent’s utility rises, whereas the private agent’s utility falls. Social welfare, defined simply as the unweighted sum of the in- dividual utilities (U1 + U2), balances these conflicting changes in util- ity. In this case, the optimal tax mix occurs with a consumption tax rate of 21% and an income tax rate of 50%. Changing the level at which government is held fixed (e.g., 10%, 20%, 30%, and 50%) affects the exact levels of the optimal tax rates but does not affect the general re- sult that an optimal tax mix exists, one that balances the wish of the public agent for a greater reliance on the income tax with that of the private agent for more use of the consumption tax. Changing the social welfare function to weight more heavily the welfare of the private agent shifts the optimal tax structure toward a greater reliance on con- sumption taxation, whereas a greater welfare weight for the public agent leads to heavier income taxation at the social optimum. Importantly, how does the optimal tax mix for a corrupt economy compare to that for an economy without corruption? Recall that, in the absence of corruption, public goods are provided competitively at Barreto, Alm / CORRUPTION 17 TABLE 4: Steady State: Tax Substitution with Constant Government Size 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 U2 + U1 = 9.161 9.164 9.165 9.165 9.164 9.162 9.159 U1 = 4.220 4.213 4.206 4.202 4.198 4.188 4.178 U2 = 4.941 4.951 4.959 4.963 4.966 4.974 4.980 k1/k2 = 0.171 0.177 0.183 0.185 0.188 0.193 0.198 ψ/y = 0.192 0.188 0.183 0.180 0.178 0.173 0.169 τ= 0.550 0.530 0.510 0.500 0.490 0.470 0.450 ω= 0.031 0.104 0.177 0.213 0.250 0.324 0.398 Tax revenue/y = 0.450 0.450 0.450 0.450 0.450 0.450 0.450 least cost. Recall also that the private agent’s welfare rises as the tax mix shifts toward income taxes and away from consumption taxes be- cause both agents pay consumption taxes but only the private agent pays income taxes. Consequently, the tax mix in a “clean” economy relies more heavily on income taxes than on consumption taxes; put differently, in a “corrupt” economy, the optimal tax mix makes greater use of consumption taxes than of income taxes. Figure 7 depicts this result. 4. CONCLUSION Our main result suggests that holding the relative size of govern- ment constant, the presence of corruption generates an optimal tax mix that relies more heavily on consumption taxes than on income taxes. This result is consistent with standard tax advice given to devel- oping countries, especially those in which corruption is endemic: De- veloping countries should rely more heavily on indirect taxation than on direct taxation (Newbery and Stern 1987). This result is derived in a model in which the (relative) size of gov- ernment is held constant. Our model also allows us to investigate how social welfare varies with tax structure when the size of government is allowed to vary; that is, we are able to calculate the optimal (or wel- fare-maximizing) size of government and to compare the optimal size of government in a corrupt versus a clean economy. To present this more fully, the relative government size (irrespective of the specific 18 PUBLIC FINANCE REVIEW Figure 6: Tax Substitution Given a Constant Government Size Figure 7: Tax Substitution Effects on Welfare at the Steady State: No Corruption tax mix that generates it) is plotted in Figures 8, 9, and 10 against the utility of the public agent, the utility of the private agent, and social welfare (the sum of the utilities of the two agents), respectively. The Barreto, Alm / CORRUPTION 19 Figure 8: Relative Size of Government Versus Welfare at the Steady State: Pub- lic Agent optimal government size necessarily occurs at the global welfare- maximizing tax mix. In the presence of a corrupt public sector, there is still an important role for government; that is, neither agent achieves maximum utility in an economy with no government, even when that government is corrupt. The optimal government size from the public agent’s point of view is roughly 30% (Figure 8), whereas the optimal government size from the private agent’s point of view is only 13% (Figure 9). The government size that maximizes social welfare bal- ances these conflicting objectives at 20% (Figure 10). However, it is not surprising that the optimal size of government is greater in a clean economy than in a corrupt economy (Figure 11).15 When there is no corruption, the optimal size of government is signifi- cantly greater, at 80%, because the negative effects of corruption on social welfare via the implied loss in production of the public con- sumption and production goods are no longer present. In short, fiscal policy is decidedly affected by corruption and af- fected in ways that are largely consistent with expectations. Spe- cifically, a corrupt economy should have a tax mix that relies more 20 PUBLIC FINANCE REVIEW Figure 9: Relative Size of Government Versus Welfare at the Steady State: Pri- vate Agent Figure 10: Relative Size of Government Versus Welfare at the Steady State: So- cial Welfare
DMCA.com Protection Status Copyright by webtailieu.net